Price decision under perfect competition Definition of Perfect Competition: The concept of perfect competition was first introduced by Adam Smith in his book "Wealth of Nations". Later on, it was improved by Edgeworth. However, it received its complete formation in Frank Kight's book "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit" (1921). Perfect competition is a form of market in which there are a large number of buyers and sellers competing competing with each other in the purchase and sale of goods, respectively and no individual buyer or seller has any influence over the price. Thus perfect competition is an ideal form of market structure in which there is the greatest degree of competition. Leftwitch has defined market competition in the following words: "Prefect competition is a market in which there are many firms selling identical products with no firm large enough, relative to the entire market, to be able to influence market price". According to Bllas: "The perfect competitionis characterized by the presence of many firms. They sell identically the same product. The seller is a price taker". Basic
y
assumptions required for conditions conditions of pure competition to exist : Many
small firms , each of whom produces an insignificant percentage of total
market output and thus exercises no control over the ruling market price. y
Many
individual buyers, none of whom has any control over the market price ² i.e. there is no monophony power
y
Perfect
freedom of entry and exit from the industry. Firms face no sunk costs - entry
and exit from the market is feasible in the long run. This assumption ensures all firms make normal profits profits in the long run r un y
Homogeneous
products are supplied to the markets that are perfect substitutes. This
leads to each firms being passive ´price ´price takersµ and faci ng a perfectly elastic demand curve for their product y
Perfect
knowledge ² consumers have readily available information about prices and products from competing suppliers and can access this at zero cost ² in other words, there are few transactions costs involved in searching for the required information about prices
y
y
No
externalities arising from production and/or consumption which lie outside the market Profit
maximization. For perfect competition to exist, the sole objective of the firm must be to get m aximum profit.
ara
¡
¢
£
¡
£
¤
r
¢
¥
¦
¤
¥
£
¦
§
f p rf ¢
Tabl
%
&
'
3
5
(
&
(
2
0
7
r p rf a a r ppl . '
(
(
&
5
(
'
)
3
(
(
)
&
0
5
0
6
ly
0
'
(
5
5
7
7
¢
£
¤
£
§
p
¨
¢
¤
¥
¤
¥
1
2
(
0
3
0
3
7
)
7
(
3
(
©
ar
2
3
3
1
4
7
(
0
2
3
0
6
3
)
(
3
)
)
3
6
(
5
3
(
0
6
5
(
5
'
0
¦
¨
0
(
abl q a 3
7
5
&
Market su
¥
abl
¢
¥
r
by
2
6
(
0
3
'
3
0
&
(
y
'
Demand Curve
C
!
(
¨
Perfect
"
ar
¢
1 1 C a a t i ti
p v ar pr pply. Eq l br pr pply rv , r a w )
§
l curve
'
'
a (
0
0
2
©
!
6
0
6
(
3
&
0
(
l v lw a , (
(
&
(
'
(
'
3
5
. :
petiti
#
¢
!
$
ra
6
3
(
)
)
0
6
3
'
1
&
(
q al 7
2
0
1
f a
0
6
&
1
0
6
(
'
(
f r rv q a 1
)
)
7
7
&
(
1
5
(
0
3
0
y
f
The graph shows that the market price under perfect competition is determined at 45 level complying with the point of intersection of the market supply curve with market demand curve. Importance of Perfect
8
ompetition:
Perfect competition model is hotly debated in economic literature. It is argu ed that the model is based on unrealistic assumptions. It is rare in practice. The defenders of the model argue that the theory of perfect competition has positive aspect and leads us to correct conclusions. The concept is useful in the analysis of interna tional trade and in the allocation of resources. It also makes us understand as to how a firm adjusts its output in a competitive world.
Short Run Equilibrium of the Price Taker Firm: Definition of a Short Run: By short run is meant a length of time which is not enough to change the level of fixed inputs or the number of firms in the industry but long enough to change the level of output by changing variable inputs. In short period, a distinction is made of two types of costs (i) fixed cost and (ii) variable cost. The fixed cost in the form of fixed factors i.e., plant, machinery, building, etc. does not vary with the change in the output of the firm. If the firm is to increase or decrease its output, the change only takes place in the quantity of variable resources such as labor, raw material, etc. Further, in the
short-run,
the demand
curve facing the firm is horizontal. No new firms enter or leave the industry. The number of firms in the industry, therefore, remain the same. Under perfect competition , the firm takes the price of the product as determined in the market. The firm sells all its output at the prevailing market price. The firm, in other words, is a price -taker. Equilibrium
of a
9
ompetitive Firm:
The short-run equilibrium of a firm can be easily explained with the help of marginal revenue = marginal cost approach or (MR = MC) rule. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue that occurs in response to a one unit change in the quantity sold. Marginal cost is the addition to total cost resulting from the additional of marginal uni t. Since price is given for the competitive firm, the average revenue curve of a price taker firm is identical to the marginal curve. Average revenue (AR) thus is equal to marginal revenue (MR) is equal to price (MR = AR = Price). According to the marginal revenue and m arginal cost approach or (MR = MC) rule , a price taker firm is in equilibrium at a point where marginal revenue (MR) or price is equal to marginal cost The point where MR = MC = Price, the firm produces the best level of output. From this it may not be concluded that the perfectly competitive firm at the
eq l br level f p ( = = r e) ecessar ly ensur es a um pr f . e fact s that n the shor t per od, a f r m at the equilibr ium level of output is faced with four types of pr oduct pr ices in the mar et which ive r ise to following r esults: R
Q
@
A
A
A
A
@
C
B
C
@
A
D
@
D
E
F
A
E
H
G
P
I
A
B
A
C
B
A
S
D
A
T
(i)
A
U
fir m ear ns super nor mal pr ofits.
V
(ii)
fir m ear ns nor mal pr ofits.
V
(iii)
fir m incur s losses but does not close down.
V
(iv) fir m minimizes losses by shutting down. explained with the help of diagrams. V
PC: Sh t R W
X
ll these shor t r un cases of pr ofits or losses ar e
V
Eq ilib i
a
X
`
`
Y
`
b
ir m·s Demand urve = ar et r ice = ir m·s Supply urve = ar ginal ost argi al C t > Average Variable C Where c
d
e
c
f
d
i
p
g
e
e
q
h
d
r
Deter mi i g P rof it from
q
t
r
Graph:
(1) Prof it Maximizi g Pos ition: s
A fi i th sh t u a s ab al av ag t tal st (S ATC). Th sh t u h l f a diag a . t
x
u
v
t
t
w
x
v
t
v
u
x
w
t
fits wh at th b st l v l f ut ut, th fit axi izi g siti f a u ly x
x
y
x
x
w
t
v
x
w
t
w
w
t
t
w
t
v
y
w
v
w
w
x
x
u
u
v
x
w
y
x
x
y
t
v
u
w
u
t
w
x
y
ak t i titiv fi t
w
y
w
w
x ds th sh t u is x lai d with th x
y
w
w
t
u
w
w
t
t
w
w
y
v
v
w
w
t
y
u
I th figu (15.3), ut ut is asu d al g OX axis a d v u / st OY axis. W assu h that th a k t i is qual t OP. A i tak fi has t s ll its ti ut ut at this vaili g a k t i i.e. OP. The fi is i equilib iu at i t L. Where MC = MR. The i ter secti f MC a d MR determi e the qua tity f the g d the firm will roduce. t
v
w
u
x
t
w
t
y
t
w
u
y
t
t
u
v
t
y
w
t
v
t
w
w
x
w
w
x
w
v
t
x
w
w
x
t
u
w
w
y
v
t
v
w
u
t
w
y
x
v
x
x
v
x
u
w
v
y
w
w
t
w
v
u
w
w
y
w
x
v
w
t
x
v
v
x
x
v
y
After havi g determi ed the qua tity, drop a ver tical li e dow to the hor izontal axis and see what the aver age total cost ( ATC) is at that output level (point N). The competitive firm will produce ON quantity of output and sell at mar ket pr ice OP. The total revenue of the firm at the best level of output ON is equal to OPLN. Whereas the total cost of producing ON quantity of output is equal to OKMN. The firm is earning supernormal profits equal to the shaded rectangle KPLM. The per unit profit is indicated by the distance LM or PK. v
v
v
v
v
lo e . S mmin p, in t e ort r n t e firm i le t n t e lo from clo in o n.
ill not o o t of
ine
for
lon
t e lo
m t
in t e
ine
(4) Short Run shut Down (Short-run losses and the shut-down decision):
When the firm's average total cost curve lies above its marginal revenue curve at the profit maximizing level of output, the firm is experiencing losses and will have to consider whether to shut down its operations. In making this determination, the firm will take into account its average variable costs rather than its average total costs. The difference between the firm's average total costs and its average variable costs is its average fixed costs. The firm must pay its fixed costs (for example, its purchases of factory space and equipment), r ega rdless of whether it produces any output. Hence, the firm's fixed costs are considered sunk costs and will not have any bearing on whether the firm deci des to shut down. Thus, the firm will focus on its average variable costs in determining whether to shut down. The case where the firm is incurring short-run losses but continues to operate is illustrated graphically in Figure 2 (a). At the market price, P1, the firm's profit maximizing quantity is Q1. At this quantity, the firm's average total cost curve lies above its marginal revenue curve, which is the flat, dashed line denoting the price level, P1. The firm's average variable cost curve, however, lies below its marginal revenue curve, implying that the firm is able to cover its variable costs. The firm's losses from producing quantity Q1 at price P1 are given by the area of the shaded rectangle, abc d. Despite these losses, the firm will decide not to shut down in the short-run because it receives enough revenue to pay for its variable costs.
Figure 2 (b) depicts a different scenario in which the firm's average total cost and average variable cost curves both lie above its marginal revenue curve, which is the dashed line at price P2. The firm's losses are given by the area of the shaded rectangle, abed. In this situation, the firm will have to shut down in the sho r t - r unbecause it is unable to cover even its variable costs. As a general rule, a firm will shut down production whenever its average variable costs exceed its marginal revenue at the profit maximizing level of output. If this is not the case, the firm may continue its operations in the short-run, even though it may be experiencing losses.
On the other way:
Long-Run Equilibrium
of the Price Taker Firm:
Now let us analyze the profit maximizing output decision by perfectly competitive firms in the long run when all inputs and therefore costs are variable. In the long run, a manager can choose to employ any plant size required to produce the efficient level of output that will maximize profit. The plant size or scale of operation is fixed in the short run but in the long run it can be altered to suit the economic conditions. In the long run, the firm attempts to maximize profits in the same m anner as in the short run, except that there are no fixed costs. All costs are variable in the long run. Here again the firm takes the market price as given and this market price is the firm·s marginal revenue. The firm would increase output as long as the marginal revenue from each additional unit is greater than the marginal cost of that unit. It would decrease output when marginal cost exceeds marginal revenue. This way the firm maximizes profit by equating marginal cost and marginal revenue (MR = MC; as discussed above).
Quantity is set by the firm so that short-run: Price = Marginal Cost = Average Total Cost At the same quantity, long-run: Price = Marginal Cost = Average Cost Economic Profit = 0
Figure 12.2: Profit Maximizing Equilibrium in the Long Run
The firm·s long run average cost (LAC) and m arginal cost (LMC) curves are shown in Figure 12.2. The firm faces a perfectly elastic demand indicating the equilibrium price (Rs. 17) which is the same as marginal revenue (i.e., D = MR =P). You may observe that as long as price is greater than LAC, the firm can make a profit. Therefore, any output ranging from 20 ² 290 units yields some economic profit to the firm. In figure 12.2, B and B1 are the breakeven points, at which price equals LAC, economic profit is zero, and the firm can earn only a normal profit. The firm, however, earns the maximum profit at output level 240 units (point S). At this point marginal revenue equals LMC and the firm would ideally select the plant size to produce 240 units of output. Note that in this situation the firm would not produce 140 units of output at point M, which is the minimum point o f LAC. At this point marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost, so the firm can gain by producing more output. As shown in figure 12.2, at point S total revenue (price times quantity) at 240 units of output is equal to Rs. 4080 (= Rs. 17 * 240), which is the area of the rectangle OTSV. The total cost (average cost times quantity) is equal to Rs. 2,880 (= Rs. 12 * 240) which is the area of the rectangle OURV. The total profit is Rs. 1,200 = (Rs. 17 ² Rs. 12) * 240, which is the area of the rectangle UTSR. Thus, the firm would operate at a scale such that long run marginal cost equals price. This would be the most profitable situation for an individual firm (illustrated in figure 12.2). Therefore, if the price is Rs. 17.00 per unit, the firm will produce 240 units of output, generating a profit of Rs. 1,200.00. This profit is variously known as above normal, super normal or economic profit. The crucial question that one needs to ask is whether this is a sustainable situation in a perfectly competitive market i.e. whether a firm in a perfectly competitive industry can continue to make positive economic profits even in the long
run? The answer is unambiguously no. This result derives from the assumption that in a perfectly competitive market there are no barriers to entry. Recall that in a market economy, profit is a signal that guides investment and therefore resource allocation decisions. In this case, the situation will change with other prospective entrants in the industry. The economic force that attracts new firms to enter into or drives out of an industry is the existence of economic profits or economic losses respectively. Economic profits attract new firms into the industry whose entry increases industry supply. As a result, the prices would fall and the firms in the industry adjust their output levels in order to remain at profit maximization level. This process continues until all economic profits are eliminated. There is no longer any attraction for new firms to enter since they can only earn normal profits. By observing figure 12.2 you should try to work out the price that will prevail in this market in the long run when all firms are earning normal profit. Analogous to economic profit serves as a signal to attract investment, economic losses drive some existing firms out of the industry. The industry supply declines due to exit of these firms which pushes the market prices up. As the prices have risen, all the firms in the industry adjust their output levels in order to remain at a profit maximization level. Firms continue to exit until economic losses are eliminated and economic profit becomes zero, that is, firms earn only a normal rate of profit.
Others example:
Global
ompetition:
Foreign Exchange Rate
Price
of a foreign currency in terms of the domestic currency
Depreciation
Increase Decrease
Domestic
Currency
in the price of a foreign currency relative to the domestic currency
A ppreciation
of the of the
Domestic
Currency
in the price of a foreign currency relative to the domestic currency